Main

Global carbon emissions have continued to rise over the past several decades, and concentrations of atmospheric CO2 have increased dramatically. The ‘safe’ planetary boundary for emissions—understood as atmospheric concentration of 350 ppm CO2—was crossed in 19881. As of 2022, atmospheric concentrations are now 415 ppm (ref. 2), and global temperatures have reached 1.1 °C over preindustrial levels3. The Paris Agreement commits the world’s governments to limiting global temperature rise to 1.5 °C, or well below 2 °C4. The remaining carbon budgets associated with these boundaries are being rapidly depleted, and climate damages are accelerating.

Not all countries are equally responsible for the depletion of carbon budgets, however; some nations have contributed more to causing this crisis than others. This disproportionate historical responsibility is problematic from a climate justice perspective that recognizes the atmosphere as a shared commons, to which all people are entitled to a fair and equitable use5,6,7,8. Scholars have drawn on this principle to argue that carbon budgets should be shared equitably9,10,11,12 and that cumulative emissions in excess of fair shares represent a form of appropriation of atmospheric commons, which has been framed in the language of ‘climate debt’ and ‘climate coloniality’13,14,15. Acknowledging issues of equity is essential to establishing trust and buy-in to the negotiation process16.

Researchers and climate negotiators have argued that overemitting countries owe compensation or reparations to low-emitting countries for atmospheric appropriation and climate-related damages, which fall disproportionately on poorer countries that have contributed little or nothing to the crisis17,18,19,20,21. Paragraph 51 of the Paris Agreement decision document states that the agreement “does not involve or provide a basis for any liability or compensation”4. Nonetheless, legal scholars argue that options remain open for the development of a compensation and liability system under the Warsaw International Mechanism for Loss and Damage, which was created in 201322. Calls for payments for loss and damage have gained momentum, notably during the twenty-sixth Conference of the Parties (COP26) summit in Scotland23 and the COP27 summit in Egypt24, which formally established a loss and damage fund, with details to be clarified at COP28.

This Article adds to this literature—and the broader public debate—by offering an empirical method for quantifying compensation owed for the appropriation of atmospheric commons. Building on earlier work, we use an equality-based fair-share approach to calculate countries’ use of established carbon budgets, including for 350 ppm, 1.5 °C and 2 °C (refs. 9,12). This analysis allows us to determine the extent to which nations have exceeded their fair shares of the carbon budgets and appropriated atmospheric commons. We then assess countries’ projected future use of the carbon budgets if they carry on with business as usual, as well as if they pursue ambitious emissions reductions to reach ‘net zero’ by 2050, consistent with limiting warming to 1.5 °C.

The world must make every effort to respect the 1.5 °C limit, as per the Paris Agreement. If some countries appropriate more than their fair shares of the carbon budget, this has important implications. It means overemitters are disproportionately responsible for damages caused by global warming but also that other countries must effectively forgo the full use of their own fair shares to keep the world on track for 1.5 °C, mitigating more rapidly than would otherwise be required. One way to quantify the monetary value of atmospheric appropriation is by representing overshoot emissions in terms of carbon prices. In this Article, we use marginal abatement costs from the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change Sixth Assessment Report (IPCC-AR6) scenarios consistent with limiting global warming to 1.5 °C.

Our results provide an indication of how compensation for atmospheric appropriation can be quantified in a way that accounts for historical and current responsibilities, but it is beyond the scope of this study to provide a framework for practical implementation. However, we note that the climate reparations literature is increasingly considering the politics, governance and practicalities of such an approach, and our results may be useful inputs to inform the ongoing ‘Glasgow Dialogue on Loss and Damage’ established during COP2617,23,24,25,26.

Results

Our first step is to estimate levels of atmospheric appropriation by tracking historical cumulative emissions with respect to equality-based fair shares of the 350 ppm, 1.5 °C and 2 °C carbon budgets across 168 countries from 1960 to 2019, together with two forward-looking estimates between 2020 and 2050, namely (1) business-as-usual projections based on historical trends (with ‘likely’ or 66% prediction intervals) and (2) net-zero scenarios with country-specific mitigation rates that bring CO2 emissions in each country from 2020 levels to 0.1 tonnes per capita in 2050 (see Extended Data Fig. 1 for country-specific mitigation rates). We also analyse the sensitivity of our cumulative results to the 1960 start date by conducting two parallel analyses starting in 1850 and 1992 (the year the United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change was established), respectively. The estimation procedures are described in detail in Methods.

At the global scale, we find that cumulative emissions since 1960 are currently around three times beyond the 350 ppm carbon budget (exhausted in 1988), and a global emissions mitigation rate of more than 10% per year between 2020 and 2050 is needed for net zero, which would respect the 1.5 °C carbon budget (Fig. 1a). However, our business-as-usual projections suggest the world will likely deplete the 1.5 °C carbon budget by 2030 (2028–2032) and the 2 °C carbon budget by 2044 (2039–2049). We note that the 1.5 °C carbon budget and the 2 °C carbon budget are both substantially larger—and therefore riskier—than the safe 350 ppm carbon budget that respects the climate change boundary proposed by ref. 1.

Fig. 1: World and regional cumulative CO2 emissions with respect to fair shares of global carbon budgets, historical trends (1960–2019) and scenario trends (2020–2050).
figure 1

a, World. b, Global South region. c, Global North region. The historical emissions (black area), business-as-usual projected pathway (dashed line) and net-zero pathway (blue line) show cumulative emissions relative to fair shares of the 1.5 °C carbon budget (yellow line), with fair shares of 350 ppm (green line) and 2 °C budgets (red line) also shown. World and regional totals are aggregated from national values. Likely (66%) prediction intervals are shown in lighter tint around the business-as-usual projections. See Extended Data Figs. 1 and 2 for results with cumulative emissions starting from 1850 and 1992, respectively.

We performed a regional analysis to assess the depletion of carbon budgets by the global North and global South: the global North here refers to the United States, Europe, Canada, Australia, New Zealand, Japan and Israel, while the global South refers to the rest of Asia, Africa and the Americas.

There are 129 countries from the global South in our analysis, which are home to more than 80% of the total population, but their aggregate cumulative emissions surpassed fair shares of the 350 ppm carbon budget only in 2012—more than two decades after the world as a whole (Fig. 1b). If this group of countries collectively pursued ambitious mitigation following our net-zero scenario between 2020 and 2050, it would use only 50% of its 1.5 °C fair share. Our business-as-usual projections suggest this group of global South countries would likely remain within its fair share of the 2 °C carbon budget by 2050 but would likely overshoot its fair share of the 1.5 °C carbon budget in 2048 (2043–2053), judging from historical trends.

The remaining 39 countries in our analysis are from the global North, and we find this group of high-emitting countries used up its collective fair share of the 350 ppm carbon budget by 1969, then overshot its 1.5 °C fair share by 1986 and then surpassed its 2 °C fair share by 1995 (Fig. 1c). As of 2019, this group of countries has already exceeded its collective fair share of the 1.5 °C carbon budget by more than 2.5 times, with cumulative emissions measured from 1960. If this group collectively pursues ambitious mitigation to reach net zero by 2050—as many of these countries have pledged in their Nationally Determined Contributions under the Paris Agreement—our findings suggest its cumulative emissions would still be nearly three times over its 1.5 °C fair share. However, our business-as-usual projections suggest this group of global North countries will likely increase the extent of its cumulative overshoot further to 4.0 times (3.7–4.3) over its fair share of the 1.5 °C carbon budget by 2050.

We find all global North countries overshooting their 1.5 °C fair shares, and they collectively hold responsibility for the majority (91%) of cumulative overshoot between 1960 and 2019. The only countries that stay within their 1.5 °C fair shares over the same period are all in the global South (Fig. 2a). Alarmingly, total cumulative overshoot is likely to triple in absolute terms by 2050 under business-as-usual projections (Fig. 2b). Although we find cumulative overshoot of 1.5 °C fair shares in the United States, Europe and the rest of the global North would likely double in absolute terms by 2050 under business-as-usual projections, their share of total overshoot would fall to 60% due to increasing levels of overshoot from countries in the global South. Notably, we find that China would likely switch from holding 15% of total 1.5 °C undershoot in 2019 to contributing 27% of total overshoot in 2050, according to historical trends.

Fig. 2: Cumulative CO2 emissions overshoot and undershoot by country group with respect to 1.5 °C fair shares.
figure 2

a, Historical 1960–2019 period. b, Business-as-usual median projection in 2050. c, Net-zero scenario in 2050. See Extended Data Figs. 3 and 4 for results with cumulative overshoot and undershoot starting from 1850 and 1992, respectively.

By contrast, stabilizing carbon emissions by 2050 under net-zero scenarios could limit warming to 1.5 °C, and would likewise stabilize national responsibility for both averting and causing climate breakdown (Fig. 2c). We find total undershoot in our net-zero scenario would be held entirely by countries in the global South (including China), and 89% of total overshoot would be held by the global North (with the remaining overshoot held by high-emitting countries in the global South).

Overall, ambitious mitigation to reach net zero by 2050 in all countries could limit warming to 1.5 °C, but more than half (53%) of the undershooting global South’s fair shares would be appropriated in the process to balance the excess emissions of overshooting countries. We find broadly similar results with cumulative emissions starting from 1850 or from 1992, although the fair shares appropriated from undershooting countries are somewhat higher from 1850 (60%; Extended Data Fig. 3) and somewhat lower from 1992 (48%; Extended Data Fig. 4). We use these findings as inputs for the next step in our analysis; to quantify the compensation owed by overshooting countries to undershooting countries for the appropriation of atmospheric commons.

It is well established that there is a strong positive relationship between affluence and ecological pressures, including carbon emissions27,28. We investigate this relationship further for our cumulative analysis by comparing the historical level of cumulative emissions (with respect to 1.5 °C fair shares) with cumulative gross domestic product (GDP) per capita from 1960 to 2018 (the most recent year with comparable data for a large number of countries; N = 151).

We find nearly 70% of cross-national variability in cumulative GDP per capita can be explained solely by differences in cumulative emissions with respect to fair shares (adj-R2 = 0.69; Fig. 3). There is some variability across countries, notably among former USSR and Eastern European countries, which tend to have relatively higher levels of overshoot at lower levels of income. However, our linear estimates suggest each additional unit of cumulative overshoot beyond a country’s 1.5 °C fair share is significantly associated with an increase of more than US$10,000 cumulative GDP per capita (P < 0.001; we report all monetary values throughout in constant 2010 prices). These findings support the view that overshooting countries have tended to enrich themselves through appropriating more than their fair shares of the atmospheric commons.

Fig. 3: Cumulative CO2 emissions with respect to 1.5 °C fair shares versus cumulative GDP per capita, 1960–2018.
figure 3

Only countries with available GDP data covering the 1960–2018 analysis period are included (N = 151). GDP is expressed in constant 2010 prices. A statistical model estimated using two-sided ordinary least squares regression finds the following linear relationship: \(y=\mathrm{10,688}x-31\) with slope and intercept coefficient standard errors of 585 and 809, respectively (adj-R2: 0.69; F statistic: 333.8 on 1 and 149 d.f.; P < 2.2 × 10−16). One country (Luxembourg) lies beyond the chart area; see Supplementary Data 1 for results for all countries.

Building on these results, we develop a procedure for allocating financial compensation from overshooting countries to undershooting countries based on each country’s cumulative emissions with respect to 1.5 °C fair shares in a world that achieves net zero by 2050. Each overshooting country’s cumulative excess emissions in 2050 under its net-zero pathway were annualized and valued in monetary terms from 2020 to 2050 using median (and interquartile range) marginal abatement costs derived from IPCC-AR6 mitigation pathways that limit warming to 1.5 °C with no or limited overshoot (N = 73) (ref. 29). The marginal abatement costs of carbon increase over time, for example, US$198 (158–242) per tonne of CO2 in 2030 and US$547 (394–887) per tonne of CO2 in 2050. We then distributed the cumulative monetary value of excess emissions from each overshooting country to each undershooting country on the basis of the latter’s share of total undershoot emissions in 2050 under our net-zero scenario. The procedure is described in detail in Methods.

We find that cumulative financial compensation from overshooting countries to undershooting countries in a world that achieves net zero between 2020 and 2050 can be valued at US$192 (141–298) trillion (Fig. 4). The average annual compensation for each year over the 31-year period is equivalent to US$6.2 (4.5–9.6) trillion per year, or approximately 8% (6%–11%) of world GDP in 2018. Importantly, this value should be seen as compensation for the appropriation of undershooting countries’ 1.5 °C fair shares to avoid climate breakdown and is therefore additional to fairness considerations surrounding the costs incurred by countries to actually transition to net-zero emissions or to adapt to a 1.5 °C warmer world30.

Fig. 4: Cumulative compensation due from overshooting country groups to undershooting country groups (relative to 1.5 °C fair shares) based on the historical period from 1960 to 2019 and net-zero scenario from 2020 to 2050.
figure 4

Cumulative compensation is expressed in constant 2010 prices. See Extended Data Fig. 5 for results with cumulative financial compensation by country group starting from 1850 and 1992 and Supplementary Data 1 for results for all countries.

Total financial compensation due to undershooting countries decreases when historical responsibility for climate breakdown is ‘forgiven’ by assessing cumulative emissions from a later start date (and vice versa for an earlier start date), ranging from US$109 (80–170) trillion from 1992 and US$238 (175–371) trillion from 1850 (Extended Data Fig. 5). We find the United States, the European Union and the United Kingdom owe around two-thirds of the total financial compensation from overshooting countries, irrespective of the start year. Conversely, India and the undershooting countries of sub-Saharan Africa are owed around half of the total financial compensation for giving up their 1.5 °C fair shares to achieve net zero, regardless of when cumulative emissions start. By contrast, our results for China are more sensitive to the start year, ranging from 2% of total overshoot from 1992 to 16% of total undershoot from 1850.

We find the United States holds the single largest climate debt to undershooting countries at US$2.6 (1.9–4.0) trillion per year, on average, which is equivalent to 15% (11–23%) of its annual GDP in 2018 (Fig. 5a). Other overshooting regions owe non-trivial amounts, ranging from 6% to 19% of their annual GDP on a yearly basis.

Fig. 5: Average annual compensation by country group relative to average GDP by region in 2018 based on the historical period from 1960 to 2019 and net-zero scenario from 2020 to 2050.
figure 5

a, Overemitting country groups. b, Country groups within their fair shares. Annual compensation is calculated from median carbon price values, with error bars calculated from the upper and lower bounds of the interquartile range of carbon prices, derived from IPCC-AR6 scenario pathways that limit warming to 1.5 °C with no or limited overshoot (N = 73). See Extended Data Figs. 6 and 7 for results starting from 1850 and 1992, respectively.

Meanwhile, the annual financial compensation to undershooting countries in sub-Saharan Africa for achieving net zero by 2050 would be US$1.4 (1.0–2.2) trillion per year, which represents 111% (82–173%) of their regional GDP in 2018 (Fig. 5b). Financial compensation to India on a yearly basis would be equivalent to 66% (48–102%) of its GDP in 2018, and compensation to the rest of the undershooting global South, excluding China, would represent 22% (16–34%) of its regional GDP. The climate credit due to China for achieving net zero would be US$0.5 (0.4–0.8) trillion per year on average, or 6% (4–9%) of its GDP in 2018.

At the country scale, we find the average monetary value of excess emissions appropriated by the 67 overshooting countries in our analysis would be US$2,700 (1,980–4,200) per capita per year in a world that achieves net zero between 2020 and 2050. Our results suggest that this monetary value converts to an average compensation of US$940 (690–1,470) per capita per year across the 101 undershooting countries in our analysis that would have had their fair shares appropriated, which are home to most of humanity.

Ten countries would have more than 95% of their fair shares of the 1.5 °C budget appropriated to stabilize global emissions under our net-zero scenario—all in sub-Saharan Africa—and the majority of undershooting countries (N = 55) would sacrifice more than 75% of their fair shares, including India. We find this group of low-emitting countries would be entitled to receive an average annual financial compensation of US$1,160 (850–1,800) per capita from overshooting countries to begin making reparations for the appropriation of nearly the entirety of their fair shares of the 1.5 °C budget (88%, on average; Fig. 6a). Meanwhile, undershooting countries that would have less of their fair shares appropriated would likewise be entitled to less financial compensation. For example, countries with less than 25% of their fair shares appropriated in a world that achieves the net-zero target by 2050, including China, would be entitled to receive US$280 (200–430) per capita per year, on average (N = 13).

Fig. 6: Cumulative CO2 emissions in 2050 relative to 1.5 °C fair shares versus average compensation per capita across countries, based on the historical period from 1960 to 2019 and net-zero scenario from 2020 to 2050.
figure 6

a, Average annual per capita compensation owed to countries within their fair shares (N = 101). b, Average annual per capita compensation owed by overemitting countries (N = 67). Compensation is expressed in constant 2010 prices. Colours are as per Fig. 3. Country circles are sized according to population. Two countries (Hong Kong SAR (China) and Luxembourg) lie beyond the chart area; see Supplementary Data 1 for results for all countries.

Similarly, Fig. 6b shows overshooting countries closer to their fair shares would owe less compensation than countries who are far beyond their fair shares under our net-zero scenario. We find overshooting countries with excess emissions more than three times beyond their fair shares, such as Qatar and the United States, would owe US$5,750 (4,220–8,950) per capita per year to undershooting countries, on average (N = 12). Meanwhile, overshooting countries with excess emissions less than 50% beyond their fair shares, such as Iran and Venezuela, would be entitled to pay US$520 (380–800) per capita per year, on average (N = 18).

Discussion

Our results reveal the global North has already more than exhausted its equality-based fair share of both the 1.5 °C and 2 °C carbon budgets, regardless of whether fair shares are calculated from 1850, 1960 or 1992. Any further emissions on their part will entail further appropriation of the fair shares of other countries. By contrast, the global South as a region remains well within its fair share of the 1.5 °C budget. In an ambitious net-zero-by-2050 mitigation scenario, 50% of the South’s fair shares would be appropriated by wealthy nations. We find that compensation worth US$192 trillion would be owed to the undershooting nations of the global South by 2050, with an average disbursement to those countries of US$940 per capita per year.

The compensation framework we propose here is in line with existing calls for reparations in payment of climate debts, which could be adapted and applied in practice on a yearly basis using observed carbon emission values and rigorous scenario analyses hosted by a competent international authority, such as the Warsaw International Mechanism for Loss and Damage. The benefits of this country-specific framework are (1) it acknowledges historical responsibility by overemitting countries, (2) it provides fair compensation to countries still within their fair shares and (3) it can accommodate changes in emissions trajectories and carbon prices over time. The financial contributions that we quantify here should be seen as rough first approximations.

There are debates about what year to use as a baseline for calculating responsibility for historical emissions, with studies often providing a range of different start dates7,10,31. We take a similar approach, considering 1960 to be a reasonable mid-range baseline while providing parallel analyses of cumulative emissions from 1850, a common early baseline, and from 1992, the year that the United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change was established. We consider 1960 to be a reasonable basis for compensation given that scientific understanding of the influence on atmospheric CO2 and temperature from burning fossil fuels was well understood32,33,34, and beginning to be communicated to the general public35, by the 1950s. Notably, we agree with the view that disregarding emissions before the 1990s represents an unjust way to measure historical responsibility10,11 given the importance of historical emissions noted in the preamble of the convention itself. Nevertheless, our results show undershooting countries would be entitled to substantial compensation—more than US$100 trillion—even with a 1992 baseline.

We note that the net-zero scenarios shown in Fig. 1 look highly unlikely, as indicated by our business-as-usual projections. Indeed, the latest IPCC-AR6 synthesis report indicates that existing government policies have the world on track for 3.2 °C warming by 210036. This underscores the need for much more dramatic action than governments are presently planning. Relying on supply-side efficiency improvements and technological change alone are likely to be inadequate37.

There is growing consensus that demand-side options that reduce unnecessary production and consumption, and shift to already-existing low-carbon technologies, could substantially reduce emissions while reducing inequality and improving human well-being38. In addition, mitigation consistent with 1.5 °C will probably require global North governments to adopt transformative post-growth and degrowth policies that reduce aggregate energy use directly and enable faster decarbonization39,40,41,42,43,44. Ultimately, we should understand net-zero policy as a minimum and aspire for regenerative economic systems that generously store carbon, cycle water and nurture biodiversity by consciously emulating nature’s designs and processes45,46.

The analysis presented here is necessarily limited by our methodological choices, which could be improved with further research. First, while national fair shares are calculated on the basis of the equality-based principle of atmospheric commons, other sharing principles exist and could be explored47. Second, we use carbon prices from scenarios that limit warming to 1.5 °C to quantify the value of overshoot emissions and compensation because they are consistent with our net-zero scenario and readily available in IPCC-AR6, but other approaches may be equally valid. These could include other ‘loss-based’ approaches (focusing on the value of appropriated fair shares in terms of GDP gains and losses, for example) or ‘damage-based’ approaches (focusing on the costs of climate-related damages)18. Third, our compensation estimates are based on historical and projected responsibility for emissions with no adjustments for country-specific needs or capabilities10,48. Fourth, although our business-as-usual projections include uncertainty ranges, our analysis does not fully explore uncertainties in historical estimates of emissions, population or GDP.

Finally, while emissions are normally calculated at the national level, the aggregate figures obscure significant inequalities within countries. There is evidence that per capita emissions among the poorest half of the populations in wealthy countries, such as France, the United Kingdom and the United States, are already close to the 2030 climate targets set by these countries49. Responsibility for excess emissions is held largely by the wealthy classes who have high lifestyle emissions and who wield disproportionate power over provisioning systems and national policy50.

Methods

This section summarizes how we collected historical data, estimated forward-looking projections and scenarios, calculated fair shares and distributed financial compensation to (from) countries on the basis of their cumulative undershoot (overshoot) of fair shares.

Time-series data

We collected publicly available time-series data on population51,52, CO2 emissions53,54,55,56, GDP57,58 and carbon prices29 from international sources. We combined data from multiple sources to create country-level time series spanning the relatively long 1850–2019 historical period covered by our analysis (see Supplementary Table 1 for summary descriptions of each indicator used in our analysis).

Following refs. 9,12, our approach prioritizes consumption-based CO2 emissions data available for a large number of countries from the Eora Multi-Regional Input–Output database (excluding land use, land-use change and forestry)54,56. Unlike territorial emissions accounting, consumption-based accounting accounts for the upstream emissions embodied in imports and exports and better reflects the principle of equal access to atmospheric commons. However, consumption-based data were available only from 1970, so we obtained territorial CO2 emissions from the PRIMAP-HISTTP dataset (v.2.3.1)53,55 for the earlier 1850–1969 period. We acknowledge that our analysis does not fully explore uncertainties in the historical estimates of CO2 emissions, which can vary substantially across countries and tend to be larger for consumption-based emissions due to the additional reliance on multi-regional input–output tables to account for trade flows59.

Overall, our methods yielded a balanced panel of 168 countries with CO2 emissions and population data spanning the 1850–2019 period and a slightly smaller balanced panel of 151 countries with GDP data (in constant 2010 US$) spanning the 1960–2018 period. See Supplementary Data 1 for results for all countries and Supplementary Information for additional indicator-specific methods that we used to construct each series.

Projecting business-as-usual trends

We projected business-as-usual trends in CO2 emissions for each country on the basis of annual observations over the 1960–2019 period, following the dynamic statistical forecasting methods described by ref. 12. These methods selected the best-fitting estimate from two distinct model classes for each country—(1) an exponential smoothing (ETS) state space model and (2) an autoregressive integrated moving averages (ARIMA) model—based on an automatic forecasting procedure described in detail by ref. 60 and enabled by the forecast package in R61. These time-variant nonlinear statistical models are preferable to linear estimation models (such as ordinary least squares regression) because they can account for patterns within the data and give greater weight to more recent observations.

For each country, the best-fitting estimate within each model class (ETS and ARIMA) was selected by using an automated procedure that estimates and compares a large number of defined parameter variations to fit the historical data of each country (30 for ETS and at least 17 for ARIMA)60 and chooses the model that minimizes Akaike’s information criterion, corrected for small-sample bias (AICc). Following ref. 61, the final best-fitting estimate across model classes for each country was selected on the basis of a time-series cross-validation algorithm that minimizes mean standard error (as AICc cannot be used to select models across different classes). This best-fitting model for each country was used to project median estimates of CO2 emissions from 2020 to 2050, together with 66%, or ‘likely’, prediction intervals. We joined these projected values to 2050 with our historical database and calculated cumulative emissions for each country, starting from 1850, 1960 and 1992.

Calculating net-zero scenarios

We calculated net-zero scenarios by reducing each country’s 2020 level of CO2 emissions per capita to converge at 0.1 tonnes per capita in 2050. We derived country-specific mitigation pathways that reduced emissions at a constant rate using a simple exponential function, or

$${r}_{n}=\frac{\mathrm{ln}({0.1}_{n,{t}_{2050}}/{\mathrm{CO}}_{{2}_{n,{t}_{2020}}})}{(2050-2020)+1}$$

where r is the mitigation rate required for country n to reach 0.1 tonnes CO2 per capita in 2050, starting from its initial projected level in 2020.

Although this per capita approach reduces global emissions by 97% over the 31-year period, we note that it allows 0.9 GtCO2 emissions in 2050 due to the asymptotic nature of the exponential function combined with a global population of ~9.4 billion people, which would need additional carbon dioxide removal technologies to truly achieve net zero. We have chosen this formula for transparency and simplicity (we use the same method for all countries), but we acknowledge that country-specific mitigation pathways can be derived in many ways, ideally considering respective national needs and capabilities. See Extended Data Fig. 1 for country-specific mitigation rates, which range from 17–20% per year in the highest-emitting countries, such as Qatar and the United States, to 0–3% per year in the lowest-emitting countries of sub-Saharan Africa, such as Malawi and Somalia.

We converted these mitigation rates into annual net-zero CO2 time series between 2020 and 2050 for each country n in each year t by solving the exponential function on an annual basis and multiplying this per capita series by UN population projections (medium fertility variant) over the same period, or

$${{{\mathrm{Net}}}{{\mathrm{Zero}}}}_{n,t}=({{{\mathrm{CO}}}_2}_{{n,t}_{2020}}\times {e}^{{(t-2020)r}_{n}})\times {{{\mathrm{population}}}}_{n,t}$$

We joined these scenario values to 2050 with our historical database and calculated cumulative emissions for each country, starting from 1850, 1960 and 1992.

Deriving remaining global carbon budgets

We obtained global carbon budgets remaining from 2020 with a 66% likelihood of limiting global warming to 1.5 °C and 2 °C from IPCC-AR6 (400 GtCO2 and 1,150 GtCO2, respectively)3. However, the IPCC-AR6 carbon budgets include CO2 sources from both fossil fuel combustion and land-use change, but our country-level data exclude emissions from land-use change.

To account for this difference, we obtained data on the shares of fossil fuel and land-use change in total anthropogenic emissions from ref. 62 and calculated ten-year averages over the most recent decade (90% and 10%, respectively). On the basis of these shares, we disaggregated the fossil fuel component of the IPCC global carbon budgets remaining from 2020 for 1.5 °C and 2 °C (360 GtCO2 and 1,035 GtCO2, respectively) and calculated 1.5 °C and 2 °C carbon budgets starting from 1850, 1960 and 1992.

In contrast to the 1.5 °C and 2 °C boundaries, there is no carbon budget remaining from 2020 for the 350 ppm climate boundary (CO2 concentrations are already greater than 415 ppm and rising2). We set the 350 ppm carbon budgets starting from 1850 and 1960 equal to their respective cumulative global totals in 1988 (the year that CO2 concentrations crossed this boundary). See Supplementary Table 2 for the numerical global carbon budgets that we derived for the different climate boundaries and start years used in the analysis.

Distributing national fair shares of global carbon budgets

There are different ‘top-down’ sharing principles that could be used to distribute global carbon budgets to countries, including equality, historical responsibility, respective capabilities, geographical needs and sovereignty47. Building on refs. 9,12, we developed an equality-based method that considers historical responsibility and distributes a given global carbon budget into national fair shares according to a given country’s population as a share of the global population, with populations averaged over a given analysis period (\(\overline{{{\mathrm{population}}}}\)), or

$${{{\mathrm{fair}}}\hbox{-}{{\mathrm{share}}}}_{{n,t}_{{{\mathrm{start}}}:{{\mathrm{end}}}}}^{b}={{{\mathrm{CO}}}_2\,{{\mathrm{budget}}}}_{{{{\mathrm{world}}},t}_{{{\mathrm{start}}}}}^{b}\times \left(\frac{\overline{{{{\mathrm{population}}}}_{{n,t}_{[{{\mathrm{start}}}:{{\mathrm{end}}}]}}}}{\overline{{{{\mathrm{population}}}}_{{{{\mathrm{world}}},t}_{[{{\mathrm{start}}}:{{\mathrm{end}}}]}}}}\right)$$

where the fair share for each country n is a function of the given climate boundary, b, and the cumulative analysis period, tstart:end. In our case, we analysed three climate boundaries (b = 350 ppm, 1.5 °C and 2 °C) and three analysis periods with distinct starting years that each ended in 2050 (tstart = 1850, 1960 and 1992; tend = 2050).

On the basis of the available parameter combinations, we calculated a total of eight separate fair-share values for each country using the preceding equation. Overall, our approach is underpinned by the view that all people hold a right to an equitable and fair use of the atmospheric commons. It is motivated by our specific research question, which asks whether the level of cumulative overshoot beyond a country’s fair share of global carbon budgets could serve as the basis for making climate reparations to others who are unable to make full use of their own fair shares in a net-zero world. Notably, national fair shares may change depending on the analysis period, as population shares can change with respect to the global population over time.

Comparing cumulative emissions with respect to fair shares

We present cumulative emissions with respect to fair shares of global carbon budgets in two ways. In the first case, we follow a normalization procedure similar to that employed by ref. 12, which involves dividing national cumulative emissions values by a given fair-share value on an annual basis. More specifically, all the cumulative emissions and fair-shares data for a given country, climate boundary and year were normalized for each cumulative analysis period by dividing them by that country’s 1.5 °C fair share, so this fair share is always assigned the value of one. This normalization approach anchors the 1.5 °C fair share in absolute terms (it is always one, regardless of the data), which is useful to illustrate and compare cumulative emission pathways with respect to fair shares of multiple budgets across diverse countries and regions on an equivalent scale, as shown in Fig. 1 (and Extended Data Figs. 1 and 2).

In the second case, national fair shares of each global carbon budget were subtracted from countries’ cumulative emission pathways on an annual basis to calculate the extent to which these countries have either overshot or stayed within their fair shares in each analysis period, building on the approach described by ref. 9, or

$$\begin{array}{l}{{{\mathrm{cumulative}}}\,{{\mathrm{over}}}({{\mathrm{under}}}){{\mathrm{shoot}}}}_{n,t}^{b,s}={{{\mathrm{fair}}}\,{{\mathrm{sha}}}{{\mathrm{re}}}}_{{n,t}_{{{\mathrm{start}}}:{{\mathrm{end}}}}}^{b}\\-{{{\mathrm{cumulative}}}\,{{\mathrm{emissions}}}}_{n,t}^{b,s}\end{array}$$

where cumulative overshoot (or undershoot) for each country n in each year t is a function of the given climate boundary b and the given scenario pathway s (business as usual or net zero). This approach provides a quantification of national responsibility for overshooting fair shares of a given climate boundary in absolute terms of each country’s excess emissions (or undershoot emissions). These values were summed to give total overshoot (or undershoot), and responsibility was defined on the basis of the proportion of this total held by each country, as shown in Fig. 2 (and Extended Data Figs. 3 and 4).

Compensation from overshooting to undershooting countries

We distributed financial compensation from overshooting countries to undershooting countries (both with respect to 1.5 °C fair shares) using median carbon prices from 2020–2050 derived from the IPCC-AR6 scenario database29 and each country’s net-zero scenario pathway.

We derived median (and interquartile range) marginal abatements costs of carbon over the 2020–2050 period on the basis of the 73 scenarios in the IPCC-AR6 database that report 5-year values from 2025 with a 50% likelihood of limiting warming to 1.5 °C with no or limited overshoot. Notably, these year-specific carbon prices account for the expectation of increasing marginal abatement costs over the coming decades. See Supplementary Table 3 for a summary of the numerical values we used over the 2020–2050 period and Supplementary Information for additional details.

We used these carbon prices to quantify the climate debt incurred by overshooting countries’ cumulative excess emissions beyond their 1.5 °C fair shares under our net-zero scenario as follows:

$$\begin{array}{l}{{{\mathrm{overshoot}}}{{\mathrm{debt}}}}_{i}\\=\mathop{\sum }\limits_{t=2020}^{2050}\left(\left(\frac{{{{\mathrm{cumulative}}}{{\mathrm{overshoot}}}}_{i,t=2050}}{\left(2050-2020\right)+1}\right)\times {{{\mathrm{carbon}}}{{\mathrm{price}}}}_{t}\right)\end{array}$$

where each overshooting country i’s cumulative overshoot emissions in 2050 were annualized uniformly over the 31-year period and multiplied by the respective carbon price in year t. Summing country i’s excess emissions valued in monetary terms over the 2020–2050 period yielded an estimate of the total overshoot debt incurred by its cumulative overshoot of 1.5 °C fair shares for each analysis period in a world that achieves net zero between 2020 and 2050.

We then distributed the monetary overshoot debt from each overshooting country to each undershooting country as a credit, or

$$\begin{array}{l}{{{\mathrm{undershoot}}}{{\mathrm{credit}}}}_{j}\\=\mathop{\sum }\limits_{{i}_{1}}^{{i}_{k}}\left({{{\mathrm{overshoot}}}{{\mathrm{debt}}}}_{i}\times \left(\frac{{{{\mathrm{cumulative}}}{{\mathrm{undershoot}}}}_{j,t=2050}}{{{{\mathrm{cumulative}}}{{\mathrm{undershoot}}}}_{{{\mathrm{total}}},t=2050}}\right)\right)\end{array}$$

where the sum of the overshoot debt from each overshooting country i1, i2, …, ik was distributed to undershooting country j on the basis of the latter’s share of total undershoot emissions in 2050 in each analysis period under our net-zero scenario.

Additional limitations

Some additional methodological limitations are worth noting. The data used in our analysis include only CO2 emissions and no other greenhouse gases; they do not include emissions from land-use change. Our business-as-usual projections consider time trends, but additional variables could be explored to unpack our country-specific trends, such as population, affluence and technology63. Notably, the net-zero convergence scenario we have used here does not account for the principle of common but differentiated responsibilities in light of respective national capabilities, by which countries with greater means, and with higher cumulative emissions, must decarbonize faster than the rest of the world (and vice versa for countries with lesser means). Although methods that consider respective capabilities are emerging10, often based on an income-based minimum threshold that excludes poorer countries from mitigation requirements, we have not applied them to our analysis for simplicity. It is not clear whether excluding poorer countries from mitigation would be beneficial for them in our framework, given that they would be entitled to additional compensation for achieving net zero by 2050, and these funds could go towards improving respective capabilities. A useful step for future research could be to account for country-specific decarbonization trajectories and/or to account for existing national commitments of varying strengths.

Reporting summary

Further information on research design is available in the Nature Portfolio Reporting Summary linked to this article.